|Table of Contents|

Study on the differences of big market effects in China and the U.S. from the perspective of trade costs(PDF)

《长安大学学报(社科版)》[ISSN:1671-6248/CN:61-1391/C]

Issue:
2025年02期
Page:
48-66
Research Field:
国际经济与贸易
Publishing date:
2025-05-30

Info

Title:
Study on the differences of big market effects in China and the U.S. from the perspective of trade costs
Author(s):
SUI Yuehong HAO Danyang
(Belt and Road Regional Standardization Research Center, China Jiliang University,Hangzhou 310018, Zhejiang, China)
Keywords:
international economics and trade trade cost home market effect heterogeneous stochastic frontier gravity model big market in China and the U.S. comparative advantage
PACS:
F11; F75; F74
DOI:
-
Abstract:
To study the big market effects in China and the United States from the perspective of trade costs and their differences, this study adopts the home market effect framework and proposes several hypotheses: an inverted U-shaped relationship between national economic scale and exports; a two-sided sorting spatial effect of enterprise heterogeneity; and the dominant roles of comparative advantage and big market effects in driving exports. Using bilateral trade data from China and the U.S. with 125 global trade partners from 2001 to 2021, and applying a heterogeneous stochastic frontier gravity model, the study finds that after excluding the influence of trade inefficiencies the U.S. big market effect drives import expansion, whereas China has not achieved any significant type of big market effect. China's export growth has been primarily driven by its capital-intensive comparative advantage. Quantile regression results show that the additional tariffs imposed during the Trump administration reversed the U.S. big market-driven import effect into an export effect, enhancing export efficiency. In contrast, China shifted toward exporting goods on a smaller scale or with lower efficiency. These dynamics suggest differentiated future pathways for China and the U.S. in global value chains, easing bilateral trade frictions. The study concludes that both China and the U.S. are beneficiaries of globalization, forming complementary industrial chain relationships in capital and intermediate goods trade, while remaining competitors mainly in consumer goods. Policy recommendations include strengthening domestic regulation and international coordination, guarding against economic volatility, diversifying trade partners and sustaining export growth, and emphasizing the localization and diversification of small and medium-sized enterprises.

References:

[1] KRUGMAN P.Scale Economies,product differentiation,and the pattern of trade[J].American economic review,1980(5):950-959.
[2]DAVIS D R,WEINSTEIN D E.Market access,economic geography,and comparative advantage:an empirical assessment[J].Journal of international economics,2003(1):59.
[3]BALDWIN R,HARRIGAN J.Zeros,quality and space:trade theory and trade evidence[J].American economic journal:microeconomics,2011(2):60-88.
[4]FAJGELBAUM P,GROSSMAN G,HELPMAN E.A Linder hypothesis for foreign direct investment[J].CEPR discussion papers,2011,82(1):83-121.
[5]FEENSTRA R C,MARKUSEN J R,ROSE A K.Using the gravity equation to differentiate among alternative theories of trade[J].Canadian journal of economics,2001(2):430-447.
[6]曾道智.本地市场效应的由来和研究前沿[J].城市与环境研究,2020(1):96-112.
[7]毛艳华,李敬子.中国服务业出口的本地市场效应研究[J].经济研究,2015(8):98-113.
[8]沈国兵.贸易统计差异与中美贸易平衡问题[J].经济研究,2005(6):82-93.
[9]黄万阳,王维国.人民币汇率与中美贸易不平衡问题——基于HS分类商品的实证研究[J].数量经济技术经济研究,2010(7):76-90.
[10]许培源,胡日东.中美贸易不平衡及其与美国对华投资相关性研究[J].亚太经济,2008(1):18-23.
[11]王岚,盛斌.全球价值链分工背景下的中美增加值贸易与双边贸易利益[J].财经研究,2014(9):97-108.
[12]鞠建东,马弘,魏自儒,等.中美贸易的反比较优势之谜[J].经济学(季刊),2012(3):805-832.
[13]倪红福,龚六堂,陈湘杰.全球价值链中的关税成本效应分析——兼论中美贸易摩擦的价格效应和福利效应[J].数量经济技术经济研究,2018(8):74-90.
[14]李跟强,潘文卿.中美贸易摩擦、全球价值链分工与福利效应[J].统计研究,2022(1):75-90.
[15]AMITI M,REDDING S J,WEINSTEIN D.The impact of the 2018 trade war on U.S.prices and welfare[J].CEPR discussion papers,2019(4):187-210.
[16]FAJGELBAUM P D,GOLDBERG P,KENNEDY P J,et al.The return to protectionism[J].The quarterly journal of economics,2020(1):1-55.
[17]BELLORA C,FONTAGNÉ L.Shooting oneself in the foot?trade war and global value chains[EB/OL].(2020-04-17)[2025-01-15].https://hal.science/hal-02444899v2.
[18]HANDLEY K,KAMAL F,MONARCH R.Rising import tariffs,falling export growth:when modern supply chains meet old-style protectionism[EB/OL].(2020-08-01)[2025-01-15].https://fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/workingpapers/Papers676-700/r676.pdf.
[19]李春顶,何传添,林创伟.中美贸易摩擦应对政策的效果评估[J].中国工业经济,2018(10):137-155.
[20]吕越,马嘉林,田琳.中美贸易摩擦对全球价值链重构的影响及中国方案[J].国际贸易,2019(8):28-35.
[21]齐鹰飞,LI Y F.跨国投入产出网络中的贸易摩擦——兼析中美贸易摩擦的就业和福利效应[J].财贸经济,2019,40(5):83-95.
[22]BOUET A,LABORDE D.U.S. trade wars in the twenty-first century with emerging countries:make America and its partners lose again[J].The world economy,2018(9):2276-2319.
[23]樊海潮,张丽娜.中间品贸易与中美贸易摩擦的福利效应:基于理论与量化分析的研究[J].中国工业经济,2018(9):41-59.
[24]王霞.中美贸易摩擦对全球制造业格局的影响研究[J].数量经济技术经济研究,2019(6):22-40.
[25]张杰.中美经济竞争的战略内涵、多重博弈特征与应对策略[J].世界经济与政治论坛,2018(3):1-22.
[26]李孝天.经济相互依赖视角下的中美贸易冲突:成因、启示与前景[J].国际关系研究,2019(5):109-135,158-159.
[27]张建清,陈果.基于竞合理论视角的中美贸易摩擦研究[J].经济问题探索,2019(10):100-107,164.
[28]陈明哲,庞大龙.中美贸易战:基于动态竞争的视角[J].外国经济与管理,2019(7):3-24.
[29]HEAD K,MAYER T,RIES J.On the pervasiveness of home market effects[J].CEPR discussion papers,2002(275):371-390.
[30]BEHRENS K,LAMORGESE A R,OTTAVIANO G I P,et al.Testing the home market effects in a multi-country world:the theory[EB/OL].(2004-03-29)[2025-01-15].http://repec.org/esFEAM04/up.1818.1080354839.pdf.
[31]BALDWIN R,OKUBO T.Heterogeneous firms,agglomeration and economic geography:selection and sorting[J].CEPR discussion papers,2004(3):323-346.
[32]TOSHIHIRO O.Home market effect and regulation costs—homogeneous firm and heterogeneous firm trade models[EB/OL].(2006-02-01)[2025-01-15].https://repec.graduateinstitute.ch/pdfs/Working_papers/HEIWP02-2006.pdf.
[33]钱学锋,梁琦.本地市场效应:理论和经验研究的新近进展[J].经济学(季刊),2007(3):969-990.
[34]李敬子,陈强远,钱学锋.非位似偏好、非线性本地市场效应与服务贸易出口[J].经济研究,2020(2):133-147.
[35]VENABLES A J.Equilibrium locations of vertically linked industries[J].CEPR discussion papers,1993(2):341-359.
[36]赵伟,张萃.FDI与中国制造业区域集聚:基于20个行业的实证分析[J].经济研究,2007(11):82-90.
[37]CROZET M,TRIONFETTI F.Trade costs and the home market effect[J].Journal of international economics,2008(2):309-321.
[38]FPRSID R,TOSHIHIRO O.Spatial relocation with heterogeneous firms and heterogeneous sectors[EB/OL].(2010-10-01)[2025-01-15].http://www2.ne.su.se/paper/wp10_17.pdf.
[39]ERHARDT K.On home market effects and firm heterogeneity[J].European economic review,2017(3):316-340.
[40]HANSON G H,XIANG C.The home-market effect and bilateral trade patterns[J].American economic review,2004(4):1108-1129.
[41]AMITI M.Inter-industry trade in manufactures:does country size matter?[J].Journal of international economics,1998,44(2):231-255.
[42]MATSUYAMA K.The home market effect and patterns of trade between rich and poor countries[EB/OL].(2015-07-14)[2025-01-15].https://conference.nber.org/confer/2015/SI2015/EFBGZ/Matsuyama.pdf.
[43]PFLÜGER M,TABUCHI T.Comparative advantage,agglomeration economies and trade costs[J].Journal of urban economics,2018,109(2):1-13.
[44]SCHUMACHER D,SILIVERSTOVS B.Home-market and factor-endowment effects in a gravity approach[J].Review of world economics,2006(2):330-353.

Memo

Memo:
-
Last Update: 2025-05-30